Blog

Innovation in Gene Editing and Plant Breeding

Yesterday I had the privilege of moderating a panel discussion focused on gene editing hosted by the Farm Foundation. The main speakers included:

  • Allen Van Deynze, Ph. D., Director, Seed Biotechnology Center and Associate Director, Plant Breeding Center, University of California, Davis

  • Richard Lawrence, Ph.D., Head of Genome Editing, Yield, Disease, and Quality Research, Bayer Crop Science

  • Fan-Li Chou, Ph. D., Senior Vice President, Scientific Affairs and Policy, American Seed Trade Association

  • Alison Van Eenennaam, Ph.D., Professor of Cooperative Extension in Animal Biotechnology and Genomics, University of California, Davis

You can watch the presentations and discussion here or at the video link below.

Measuring changes in supply versus changes in demand

I just finished up a new working paper with Glynn Tonsor that shows how to determine the extent to which a change in price (or quantity) results from a change in supply and/or demand. For some time, Glynn has been reporting updated retail demand indices for meat products. In this new paper, we show how to calculate an analogous supply index, which might provide a useful way to determine how much productivity is changing over time. The basic idea is that we want a way to separate changes in quantity demanded (or supplied) versus a shift in the demand curve (or the supply curve). We also show how the two indicies can be used to determine changes in consumer and producer economic well-being over time.

Here’s the motivation:

In 2015, per-capita beef consumption in the U.S. reached a record low of 54 lbs/person, falling almost 20% over the prior decade from 2005 to 2015 alone (USDA, Economic Research Service, 2020). Why? Some environmental, public health, and animal advocacy organizations heralded the decline as an indicator of their efforts to convince consumers to reduce their demand for beef; others argued, instead, the change was a result of supply-side factors such as drought and higher feed prices (e.g., Strom, 2017). Per-capita beef consumption subsequently rebounded, and in 2018 was almost 6% higher than in 2015. Dramatic fluctuations in corn, soybean, and wheat prices in the late 2000s through the mid-2010s led to similar heated debates about whether and to what extent price rises were due to demand (e.g., biofuel policy and rising incomes in China) or supply (e.g., drought in various regions of the world) factors (e.g., Abbot, Hurt, Tyner 2019; Carter, Rouser, and Smith, 2016; Hochman, Rajagopal, and Zilberman, 2010; Roberts and Schlenker, 2013). These cases highlight the challenge of interpreting market dynamics and the need for metrics that can decompose price or quantity changes to reveal underlying drivers and consequences.

We calculate the supply and demand indicies for a number of agricultural markets and time periods. First, consider changes in supply and demand in the fed cattle market since the 1950s, as shown in the figure below. The demand index trended positively from 1950 through the mid 1970s. The demand index peaked at a value of 204 in 1976, and it hasn’t been as high since. Demand fell through the 1980s and early 1990s before rebounding. Since 2010, the demand index has been at values just below the 1970’s peak. The supply index trend was positive from 1950 up till about 2000, but has been stagnant except for the past couple decades. Nonetheless, the 2018 supply index value is the highest of the entire time period since 1950. The figure shows a significant drop in the supply index that began in 2013 and bottomed out in 2015, which is likely a result of drought in the great plains and from high feed prices. The fact that the supply index dropped during this period while the demand index remained relatively flat helps provide insight into the debate discussed in the quote above.

fedcattlSDindex.JPG

One can also calculate changes in producer and consumer surplus over time. The following figure calculates the year-to-year changes. On average, from 1980 to 2018, producer surplus increased $2.7 billion each year and consumer surplus increased $0.58 billion each year. Despite these averages, there is a high degree of year-to-year variability. The largest annual change in producer surplus was $34 billion from 2015 to 2016; the largest decline in producer surplus was -$28 billion from 2013 to 2014.

fedcattlewelfare.JPG

Here’s how changes in the supply index compare for the three main meat categories. Chicken supply shifts have far outpaced that for hogs or cattle. The 2018 chicken supply index value is 380, meaning chicken supply is (380-100) = 280% higher than in 1980. By contrast, hog and beef supply are only 66% and 28% higher, respectively, than in 1980. These differences are likely explained by differential productivity patterns in these sectors. The rise in hog productivity since 2000 corresponds with a time period over which the industry became increasingly vertically integrated, increasingly mirroring the broiler chicken sector. The much longer biological production lags in beef cattle (which range from two to three years from the time a breeding decision is made until harvest) and less integrated nature of the beef cattle industry help explain the smaller increases in the supply index in this sector as compared to pork and chicken. We also show, in the paper, that these supply indicies correlate in intuitive ways with changes in factors like feed prices, drought, and aggregate U.S. agricultural total factor productivity.

meatsupplyindicies.JPG

One of the useful aspects of the supply and demand indicies is that they can be applied for highly disaggregated geographic units. To illustrate, we calculated U.S. county-level supply indicies. Here are the changes in U.S. supply indicies in the past couple years relative to 2000. Perhaps surprisingly, many areas of Ohio, Indiana, and southern Illinois have experienced negative corn supply shocks in 2016-2018 relative to 2000. The expanded geographical area of U.S. corn production (e.g more acres in the Dakotas) over this period helped mitigate national corn market effects of the adverse Eastern Cornbelt supply shocks. Note that corn yields and total production have increased significantly in many of the red counties over time, and this illustrates the importance of calculating a supply index rather than just looking at yield or production. The supply index gives us a feel for how much more (or less) is produced in 2018 relative to what we would have expected if the level of technology, weather, etc. were the same as in the year 2000.

cornsupplyindex.JPG

There is a lot more in the paper.

Malthusian Inversion

I’ve noticed several articles in the past few weeks talking about slowing or even falling population growth. This article in the Economist discussed the fact that South Korea’s fertility rate is now below replacement level (i.e., fewer babies are being born than there are parents), and their figure shows the strong negative correlation between income (or GDP) of a country and a country’s fertility rate. The richer we get, it seems the fewer babies we want or need. Then, came this opinion article in the New York Times a couple days ago about the “Chinese Population Crisis,” in which Ross Douthat argues, “Unlike most developed countries, China is growing old without first having grown rich.”

We’ve all probably been adequately exposed to the concerns and problems associated with over-population from the writings of Malthus to Ehrlich’s Population Bomb. Less well appreciated are the benefits and costs associated with a falling population. For one take on the potential concerns, see this 2013 piece by Kevin Kelly entitled the “Underpopulation Bomb.” He states the problem as follows:

This is a world where every year there is a smaller audience than the year before, a smaller market for your goods or services, fewer workers to choose from, and a ballooning elder population that must be cared for. We’ve never seen this in modern times; our progress has always paralleled rising populations, bigger audiences, larger markets and bigger pools of workers. It’s hard to see how a declining yet aging population functions as an engine for increasing the standard of living every year.

A smaller population would no doubt produce some benefits. Probably the most obvious benefit is that a smaller population would lessen human’s demands on our environment and natural resources. There is already evidence of this de-materialization. Check out Andrew McAfee’s book More from Less, where he argues that technology has led us past peak demand for many natural resources.

Among the adverse consequences, however, of falling population is likely to be downward pressure on farm incomes. The Malthusian concern implied a large population that was incapable of sufficiently feeding itself. For humanity writ large, this outcome would have been a tragedy. Farmers (or at least land owners), however, would have likely benefited from this dire outcome. More people demanding more food would have driven up food prices, land prices, and farm income. Innovation and productivity growth, fortunately, prevented the hunger problems that would have accompanied a rising population.

One crude way to see whether population growth is out-pacing the effect of innovation is to look at the long-term trend in food and agricultural prices. Here is a graph I created based on USDA data on three major commodity crop prices over time. The long-term trend is negative, suggesting innovation has outpaced the effects of population and income growth.

cropprices.JPG

Lower prices seems bad for farmers, but if they are able to sell more output using fewer resources, they also benefit (see this paper by Alston for some discussion on the farmer benefits and costs from innovation). Still, it is probably safe to say that farmers and the agricultural sector have largely come to expect a rising world population to support demand growth and offset some of the downward pressure on prices. Population projections suggest that expectation may not hold out into the future.

Indeed, research by my Purdue colleagues Uris Baldos and Tom Hertel suggests the effects of population on crop prices is likely to be much lower than what we’ve experienced in the past. They consider the effect of three factors on crop prices and production: population, income, and innovation. From 1960 to 2006, their findings indicate that the effect of innovation pushed down crop prices more than rising income and population pushed up prices, leading to an overall fall in prices, consistent with the graph above. What do they predict for the future based on expected trends in innovation, population, and income? Falling prices. They predict that, going out to 2050, the price increasing effects of population will be about half what they were from 1960 to 2006. Thus, rather than the Malthusian population bomb, we seem to be heading to a sort of Malthusian inversion.

It’s also important to note that population growth will be unevenly distributed across the world. Data and projections from the United Nations show very different anticipated population trends in low-, middle-, and high-income countries. Here is a figure I created based on their data. In 1950, population was 45%, 70%, and 82% lower than it is today in high-, middle-, and low-income countries. By 2010, the UN is projecting population will be 3%, 23%, and 220% higher in high-, middle-, and low-income countries.

population2.JPG

The implications for U.S. farmers are many fold. For one, demand growth (at least from population growth) is likely to occur outside this country, highlighting the importance of trade. Within the U.S., rising income, and demand for quality, may play an increasingly important role in supporting farm incomes in the years to come. Finally, flat or declining population, along with innovation, have the potential to have positive environmental outcomes, and it will important to think about appropriate farm policy in light of these trends.

Time to give thanks for affordable and sustainable turkey

That’s the title of an article I just wrote for The Conversation.

Here’s the whole thing:

Americans will eat about 210 million turkeys this year, amounting to over 16 pounds per person. Much of that will be eaten on Thanksgiving Day.

Over time, our Thanksgiving meal has become considerably more affordable. Turkey will probably average about US$1.40 per pound across the country in November 2019, which is less than half the price consumers were paying for turkey in the 1970s in inflation-adjusted terms.

How has turkey become so much more affordable? It turns out there isn’t a single factor, but rather a web of innovations.

The truth about turkey

It’s worth dispelling a few myths about the turkey industry first.

All farm-raised turkeys are supposed to be hormone-free.

For one thing, turkeys aren’t given any added growth hormones – doing so is illegal. It’s also illegal to sell turkey with antibiotic residues.

Also, all turkeys are raised cage-free in large, open barns.

Why aren’t more turkeys raised free-range, which means they are allowed to move outside with some freedom? It might initially sound great for turkeys to live outdoors – unless it’s snowing or raining or above 100 degrees.

It might also be fine unless there are roaming hawks, coyotes, dogs – or even wild birds. In 2015, the turkey industry was devastated by avian influenza that cost producers $225 million. Many experts believe the outbreak was caused by the introduction and spread of the disease by wild birds.

Bringing turkeys indoors allows farmers to protect the animals from weather, predators and disease, and it also enables farmers to more closely monitor their diets and health.

Spending less, eating more

Due to innovations in housing and genetics, it now takes less time and less feed to grow a turkey to market weight than it used to.

In the 1970s, the U.S. raised an average of about 125 million turkeys per year and produced about 1.9 billion pounds of turkey meat each year, meaning each turkey produced a little over 15 pounds of meat. This year, the country is projected to produce almost 25 pounds per bird.

This has led to increased affordability for Thanksgiving meals, but it has also had important implications for sustainability.

Let’s suppose Americans want to enjoy the amount of turkey we will actually consume as a nation this year – about 5.3 billion pounds – but we wanted to do that using 1970s technology. How many more turkeys would we need today had we not innovated to increase the amount of meat per bird from 15 to 25 pounds?

The answer is 132 million more turkeys.

That’s 132 million more turkeys that would have emitted waste, created greenhouse gas emissions and required water and feed. Growing that extra feed would have required more land, fertilizer and pesticides.

We were able to save those extra 132 million turkeys because we were innovative and used scientific developments and trial and error to figure out how to satisfy the wants of a much larger population using fewer of our natural resources.

That’s something to be thankful for.

Some French Reflections

I was fortunate to spend the better part of 2011 on sabbatical in Paris working with the French National Institute for Agricultural Research (INRA) and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Stephan Marette from INRA was a fantastic host.

Although I have returned many times since then to attend conferences and serve on an INRA advisory board, last week was the first time I revisited the city and our old neighborhood with my family. Here are a few reflections on the trip that relate to some of the themes on this blog.

1) We spent one morning on a food tour with a French chef. He took us to some familiar spots and some new ones too. In the course of conversation, I mentioned that I’d worked some with INRA, and I found his reaction interesting. For context, INRA is a bit like the USDA Agricultural Research Service (ARS) and a bit like the USDA National Institute for Food and Agricultural Research (NIFA), except rather than indirectly funding university professors through state agricultural experiment stations (as NIFA does in the US), INRA directly employs many PhD scientists who are housed at universities in addition to scientists at their own facilities. In any event, my guess is that if you mentioned ARS or NIFA to a chef in, say, New York, Chicago, or LA, they’d have no idea what you were talking about. ARS or NIFA who? But our French chef knew exactly who INRA was - and apparently he wasn’t much of a fan. He said that INRA only cares about producing more quantity and didn’t care about food quality, the later of which he argued was of greater importance to French consumers. I don’t think that characterization is exactly true (INRA does a lot of research on diets, health, food quality, and sustainability), but his perception of their objectives and purpose is nonetheless interesting and not entirely inaccurate. To the extent American consumers and taste-makers are familiar with US agricultural research agencies and universities, I wonder if they’d say the same? The research is clear that agricultural research produces significant benefits, but it is also true that future funding for agricultural research will depend, in part, on public support. That’s why we have to continue to find new ways to articulate the value of productivity enhancing research (for example, focusing on sustainability) and highlight the agricultural research that improves the both the price and the quality of food for consumers.

2) Given French consumer’s aversion to GMOs, attempts to ban glyphosate, and more, one might be tempted to argue that the French are more fearful of food safety risks. But, that can’t be exactly true. Below are a few pictures I snapped on the recent trip. These are not out of the ordinary in any way, but items one can find on the streets or usual supermarkets in Paris. What foods are available? Unrefrigerated eggs, unrefrigerated milk (it’s ultra high temperature pasteurized) sitting out next to the laundry detergent, cheeses from unpasteurized milk, hog legs (with hoof intact), raw rabbit carcasses for sell by street vendors, and much more. Many Americans I suspect would be very fearful of these common French foods. The French seem more accepting of “natural” food risks and less accepting of “modern/technological” food risks relative to Americans, although the example of the ultra-high pasteurized milks runs counter to that theme.

parispics.JPG

3. The French seem acutely interested in the origin/provenance of food and they often seem to use this attribute as a proxy for quality in the same way many Americans use brands. One of my current PhD students, Kendra Rash, is presenting some research at the upcoming meeting of the Agricultural and Applied Economics Association. We are analyzing some data from an experiment conducted by Laurent Muller and Bernard Ruffieux with French consumers related to the value of different types of information. We found that information on origin is more highly valued than information on brand, price, organic, and more. I was a bit skeptical of this finding (mainly because other research I’ve done in the US shows origin to be a relatively unimportant food value), but my resent visit was reassuring and suggests our French findings are probably right. A good example is wine. In the US, we normally shop for wine by grape variety (Cabernet, Merlot, or Pinot Noir), but in France, wine is typically advertised by location and vineyard (and one is supposed to know which types of grapes are grown there).

4. Despite the differences, I’ll point to one of my favorite papers by by Pierre Dubois, Rachel Griffith, and Aviv Nevo  that appeared in the American Economic Review. In many ways, their results suggest the food preferences of the French and Americans are not all that different; but our different economic systems alter the relative prices and food options available to us leading to different food choices. Here’s what I had to say about it when the paper first appeared about six years ago.

I find these results interesting because there are many Americans who seems to subscribe to a view that the French have some kind of moral superiority when it comes to food and weight. I read these results to say that the French are, in large part, just responding to the economic incentives they face. And while they consume fewer calories than we do, it isn’t all that clear they’re better off given that they must pay more for many of the foods they desire than do Americans.